Genetic discrimination saves lives

Thanks to recent technological innovations, companies like 23andme are now able to offer comprehensive genetic profiles that can reveal predispositions towards certain health problems, and allow patients to take proactive measures to prevent them. Unfortunately, this potentially lifesaving diagnosis will not be available to most individuals because of so-called “genetic privacy” laws, such as the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination Act, passed by the House earlier this year. One common argument used to justify such laws, is that genetic profiling will lead to a “second-class” of people who cannot obtain insurance or employment. Like most “ethical dilemmas” attributed to technology, this “Gattaca argument” demonstrates a lack of understanding of individual rights and basic economic principles. An analogy is useful to understand its flaws:

Suppose that you wanted to buy a used car. You have a choice of two dealerships: One dealership will provide the full specifications of the car, offer a test drive, let you look under the hood, provide a complete history from a trustworthy third-party, let you take it to your own mechanic, and even let you take the car back after a few days if you don’t like it. The other dealership tells you the year and model of the car and allows you to look at it, and that is it. Take it or leave it. Which dealership would you prefer?

Suppose that used car dealerships lobbied for a law that limited your information about their cars. (Such laws are common for doctors, lawyers, and drug companies, who face numerous restrictions on their freedom to advertise.) Who benefits from such a policy? First, due to the increased risk of purchasing a lemon, the value of used cars will fall dramatically. Owners of reliable cars will now prefer to keep their cars longer, while owners of lemons will prefer to sell. Less people will be able to afford a decent used car, and more will be stuck with cars they don’t want. There will be less incentive for car owners to maintain their cars, since their resale value will fall, as will the quality of used cars on the market. The auto dealers margins will go up, but their sales will shrink. New dealers will find it more difficult to enter the market because reputation will become more important than the prices and quality of individual cars. Much more effort will be spent on both advertising and researching reputable dealers. The overall effect will be to raise costs for everyone, discourage responsible ownership, increase fraud and deception, and benefit incumbent dealers at the expense of newer competitors.

Consider the consequences of such an egalitarian policy if it applied to health insurance. If the government completely outlawed discrimination based on all risk factors, insurance companies have to offer all customers a single rate. Healthy young women would be quoted the same rate as overweight, elderly men. What would be the result? It does not take an economist to predict that rates would immediately rise, as healthy people, refusing to pay for their neighbor’s health risks, stopped using insurance altogether. As the young and healthy jump ship, insurance companies would have to increase rates, accelerating the trend. Without further government interference, the health insurance business would disappear completely, shortly after millionaires on their deathbeds became the only people able to afford policies.

While such drastic restrictions on the ability of insurers to discriminate seem unlikely, the same principles apply to less restrictive measures, as well as “universal” insurance schemes. In response to the higher insurance premiums that these laws create, the public lobbies legislatures for price controls on health insurance and subsidies for the uninsured. Insurers and taxpayers respond to the growing costs of health welfare laws by pushing legislation that makes unhealthy behaviors and products (such as smoking and fatty foods) illegal. The more the government restricts discrimination based on health risks, the more pressure it faces to regulate and provide subsidies for health providers and forbid “unhealthy” behaviors by the public. Each additional restriction of insurers requires a corresponding subsidy or restriction of consumers, controls breeding more controls, until the entire healthcare industry is nationalized and freedom sacrificed for the “common good.”

Industries that do not face the odious regulatory burden of the healthcare industry have strong incentives to compete on the quality of their product. As their margins have shrunk, the total size of the market has grown. In competitive markets for used cars, some dealerships give cars expert inspections, refuse to buy lemons, and advertise their pricing up front.

If discrimination based on comprehensive genetic screening is legal, we can expect health providers to tailor plans according to our individual risk factors. That might be to the disadvantage of a minority of high-risk individuals, but greater information about risk factors will lower uncertainty, and thus lower rates overall. Furthermore, insurers will offer incentives to people who take proactive steps to discover health risks and take steps to alleviate them. Expensive procedures such as frequent biopsies or preemptive removal of organs might be fully covered for individuals whose genetic profiles uncover a high cancer risk.

If individuals are concerned with keeping the results of their genetic screenings private, they should ensure that screeners like 23andme are contractually obligated to keep their test results private, and prosecute them for the full damages resulting from an intentional or accidental disclosure. While the supposed purpose of genetic anti-discrimination laws is to “protect genetic privacy,” the actual effect is to remove the ability of insurers to provide financial incentives for people to get screened for potentially fatal genetic risk factors. This will only lead to unnecessary deaths from treatable genetic disorders and higher health insurance costs.

 


Posted

in

by

Comments

3 responses to “Genetic discrimination saves lives”

  1. Richard Avatar
    Richard

    The author’s arguments are totally without merit. Genetic discrimination could not possibly save lives … if anything it would make people reluctant to get tested because of the fear it would doom them or or their descendants to a life without insurance coverage. Readers beware: whatever financial incentives are being offered to you by insurance companies for these tests are nothing compared the financial incentives to the insurance company from denying you coverage once they know you have a genetic disease.

    Insurance companies, like airlines, employ price discrimination in order to maximize profit. The idea that insurance companies are in favor of genetic discrimination because it would enable more individuals to seek early/successful treatment is dubious. Could there be a benefit of genetic discrimination? Sure … it would reduce the cost of insurance for the genetically ‘robust’. And raise profits for the companies. Yet it would also eliminate access to insurance for those with genetic diseases, which is not a desirable outcome in any society.

    To see why this outcome is assured, consider the example of life insurance. Individuals who are born with handicaps/diseases that shorten life span are totally unable to obtain it. Insurance companies would have you believe they are just unlucky, and the rest of us wouldn’t want to pay the excess rates to have them included. But whats going on here is a moral hazard … insurance companies cant trust that these individuals aren’t seeking insurance precisely at the point in time they are most likely to die. If they had some reason to think these individuals were not about to die when they sought coverage, they would simply charge a higher rate to offset the increased risk associated with their disease. Then even these individuals could get life insurance if they wanted it. Case in point – astronauts doing a spacewalk face a greater than 1 in 75 chance they will die from a grain of sand ripping through their spacesuit. There is no moral hazard, however, and these astronauts can get insurance (although at very high prices).

    The genetic disease / disabled at birth situations are similar. If you have a genetic disease, insurance companies are worried that you will seek insurance right when the disease is really kicking in and likely to kill you. There is no reasonable rate they could charge to offset that moral hazard. Hence, genetic discrimination can only lead to denial of insurance coverage.

    The statement ‘it doesnt take an economist to realize … healthier people (will) jump ship’ implies that healthy people are able to forecast their needs well enough that they will opt out of insurance rates that are even moderately overpriced. They would be unwilling to seek coverage that is overpriced because of the very small minority of those with costly genetic diseases. In actuality, individuals purchase insurance even though the expected utility is negative, sometimes significantly so. This is precisely because of the uncertainty of a health disaster. Will some individuals opt to have no health insurance because prices are higher? Perhaps a few, but to suggest the departure of a few will cause cascading price increases followed by health insurance being totally inaccessible is malarkey. Insurance customers would need something close to perfect foresight to be so ready to abandon it.

    Lastly the used car analogy – specifically the notion that ‘responsible ownership’ logic applies to genetic disorders – is patently absurd. How exactly is a person with a genetic disease supposed to take steps to alleviate risks of getting the disease? In a very real sense this is something totally beyond their control.

    Rebuttals are welcome.

  2. forHealth Avatar

    Gattica.

    And people think a world described in this movie is fictional. I think we are standing on the brink.

  3. […] arguing against the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination Act last year, I […]

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *